
photo: Lisa Williams
As of 2015, the UK will be the first European country to launch a capacity mechanism that aims at rewarding power plants for the MW’s they can produce rather than the MW’s they actually generate. Similar plans are being prepared in other countries, including Belgium, France and Germany. According to Benedict de Meulemeester, CEO of international energy procurement consultancy E&C, it is understandable that energy companies lobby for capacity schemes, but governments should not heed them. Capacity payments, he argues, are an unnecessary subsidy that will only drive prices up for end consumers: they are an expensive solution for a problem that does not exist.
Those among you that have been buying energy long enough to remember the regulated markets, will know that these prices contained important capacity components. The regulated tariffs paid for all elements of power supply: production, the supply itself and the grid utilization. As these tariffs were based on a dual structure of euro’s per kW (of capacity) and euro’s per MWh (of consumption), the single, monopolist utility received money (for the capacity payments) even when the consumption was very low.
When markets were liberalized, the different utility functions were split up. Grid utilization remained a (regionally) monopolistic market and continued to receive money based on a regulated tariff with the dual kW and MWh structure. That’s quite logical. Grid companies have high Capex and fixed costs, due to the high investments that are necessary for building the grids. A grid tariff with a high capacity component means that the grid companies continue to enjoy stable income, even when the number of MWh’s travelling over their infrastructure is going down sharply. The capacity-based payments are therefore creating a stable investment climate. This is precisely what the monopolistic utility deal is all about. The government gives the utility the certainty of clientele (the monopoly) and of stable income (fees independent of the consumption). The counter-side of that deal is the fact that the monopolistic utility is regulated. The government determines the tariffs and can make sure that this doesn’t lead to excessive profit-making by the monopolistic utilities.
One of the reasons that power markets have so readily embraced marginal cost economics is the overall cost structure of power plants. In an almost perfect way, the power plants with the lowest variable costs have the highest fixed costs and vice versa.
The liberalization was all about introducing competition in the production and supply functions of the utilities, the so-called commodity part of the energy bill. Interestingly, the capacity components all but disappeared from commodity pricing. The whole market organized itself on a purely “per MWh” basis.
As far as the production or wholesale market is concerned, the powerful marginal cost pricing mechanism was introduced. Marginal cost pricing basically comes down to the following:
- Let’s say that on a given hour, all the power stations within an electrical system (e.g. the Belgian market), can produce 12 million kW of capacity. (For simplicity’s sake, I’m disregarding the impact of cross-border trading.)
- You can draw up for that hour a so-called “merit order” by ranking the power stations (and the KW’s that they can produce) according to their marginal cost, the cost that the power plant needs to make to produce the extra MWh. All fixed costs, such as Capex, are obviously excluded from marginal cost, as they have been made already. In the case of power plants, marginal cost is almost exclusively fuel cost, regardless of whether you produce the MWh or not. As a merit order goes from small to large, it will start with renewable energies, that have zero fuel costs, go on to the nuclear power stations, with their low fuel costs, and then, at the far end of the curve coal-fired and/or gas-fired power stations, depending on the relative cost of coal and gas at the moment. (For simplicity’s sake, I’m disregarding the impact of carbon prices on marginal cost pricing here. I’m also disregarding oil-fired power stations as they have become quite rare.)
- Let’s say that during that hour the demand for power, what all consumers together need, is 10 million kW.
- If we look back at our merit order now, we can draw a line, passing vertically through the curve exactly at 10 million kW.
- Now let’s say that the power station that – according to the merit order – can produce that 10 millionth kW, is a gas-fired power station with a 50% efficiency, and the natural gas price at that moment is 25 euro per MWh. This means that this marginal power station has a marginal cost of 50 euro per MWh as you need 2 MWh’s of gas to produce 1 MWh of electricity.
- Now here comes the nice thing. Let’s say that the market is willing to pay 50 euro per MWh for supply of electricity at that moment, i.e. everybody pays 50 euro per MWh for each of the 10.000 MWh delivered during that hour. This means that every power station on the merit order before the marginal power station will make a profit and that the marginal power station itself is break-even. In this case, the supply will exactly match the demand. If the market wants to pay only 49 euro per MWh, then the marginal power station will refuse to supply. A shortage occurs, pushing prices up until you reach the equilibrium.
- If you repeat this search for the equilibrium at the marginal cost of the marginal plant for every hour, than you can make sure that no power station ever has to make a loss on variable cost, every producer is always sure that he has a positive cash-flow with more money coming in from the electricity sales than money flowing out for buying fuel.
For those power stations to the left side of the marginal power station on the merit order, these positive cash-flows are the money that they have available for covering their fixed costs.
Figure 1: Marginal cost pricing for power supply
The exact size of the marginal cost depends on a variety of parameters:
- The demand itself. In hours of high demand, the price will be higher than in hours of low demand.
- The composition of the merit order. Expansion of the overall capacity of power stations with low variable cost will cause marginal costs to go down.
- The fuel costs. If gas and/or coal prices go down, marginal costs go down.
Marginal cost economics have installed themselves in wholesale electricity markets (both spot and forward) in a way that I consider to be of almost aesthetic beauty (I am aware how geeky this sounds). I’ll come back on that in a later blog article. One of the reasons that power markets have so readily embraced marginal cost economics is the overall cost structure of power plants. In an almost perfect way, the power plants with the lowest variable costs have the highest fixed costs and vice versa. Being on the left side of the merit order, high investment-cost power plants like renewables or nuclear, will always be “in the money”, meaning that they can produce and turn in positive cash-flow whenever they are capable (unless their combined supply is larger than the demand, something we’ve seen recently in Germany, resulting in negative spot prices). As these are the power plants with the highest capex, it also means that they have most euro’s available for paying back the investments. On the other side of the merit order, gas-fired power stations might have less hours during which they turn in money, but then they also have the lowest investment costs.
I am not surprised that utilities call for the governments to help, to subsidize. Because in the end, whatever shape it takes, capacity payments are a subsidy.
In the retail markets, payments of the commodity (or the deregulated) part of the electricity bill is in almost every country of Europe on an exclusively per MWh basis. Some incumbent suppliers have continued to include capacity components in their commodity pricing, but most have now given up. Either they buy the electricity on a per MWh basis in the wholesale market. Or they have an opportunity cost in euros per MWh when they source directly from their production – they could have sold it in the wholesale market at a price in euro per MWh. Therefore, selling it on to their retail market customers in euro per MWh is the simplest, most transparent and lowest risk option, which explains why it has been widely adopted.
Why are governments thinking about introducing capacity payments again?
Marginal cost pricing is by its essence more volatile than pricing according to tariffs that contain fixed cost elements such as capacity components. Prices will drop lower and rise higher. Volatility makes everyone nervous, including governments. Let’s explain this with the example of Germany. In the last three years, the wholesale prices of electricity in Germany have dropped to a historically low level due to a combination of factors:
- Like in most countries, power demand in Germany has dropped, meaning that the vertical line indicating the marginal power plant has moved to the left, causing plants on the right side of the curve to be ‘out of the money’ during many hours.
- Germany has seen an exponential expansion of its renewable power production. As all of these are on the left side of the curve, they have pushed the coal- and gas-fired power stations to the right, making it more difficult for them to be ‘in the money’.
- After the announcement of a nuclear phase-out in 2000, utilities in Germany and surrounding countries like the Netherlands have launched an intensive investment campaign in coal- and gas-fired power stations, due to which it is now quite crowded on the right side of the curve.
- Low coal and carbon prices have made the marginal cost price of coal-fired power stations drop dramatically, dragging the power price along with it.
Fig. 2: German power cost reduction explained with marginal cost economics
Utilities are obviously complaining. They are not only seeing how assets are being pushed out of the money, the lower cash-flows on the assets in the money are also weighing on their profitability. The big losers are the gas-fired power stations. The combination of low coal, carbon and marginal prices with relatively high gas prices has pushed them far out of the money. These utilities are therefore lobbying actively for the installation of a capacity market or some other form of subsidizing power stations so that they continue to receive money even when they can’t sell their MWh’s because they are out of the money. Peter Terium, the CEO of large German utility RWE, for example, defends the introduction of a capacity markets with the words: “you don’t pay the firemen only when there is a fire” (Handelsblatt, 4th of March 2014).
The German Energy Minister Sigmar Gabriel seems to be hesitating whether he should give in to these calls for the creation of a capacity market or not. He calls for regional solutions rather than rolling it out on a national scale. Surprisingly, the UK, which was the first country to fully embrace energy market liberalization, is now also the first country heading for the introduction of a capacity market. The problem of the UK market is different from the problem in Germany. In the UK, policies to switch from coal- to gas-fired power generation, a nuclear phase-out and hesitant renewable energy policies have resulted in a production park with a very large share of gas-fired power generation (40%). You simply have a crowded right side of the curve of your merit order, meaning that too many power stations are out-of-the-money or just very slightly in-the-money. And as gas-fired power stations are (or were?) about the only ones for which it is (or was?) possible to obtain a permit, the government sees a need to intervene.
I have worked in the energy sector for 15 years and during that whole period I have heard about these threats of running out of power production capacity. The lights are still burning …
I find it very logical that energy companies are not happy with a situation of low profitability in which they struggle to pay back their investments. And giving its track record, I am not surprised that utilities call for the governments to help, to subsidize. Because in the end, whatever shape it takes, capacity payments are a subsidy. It’s the government organizing an extra source of income for the utilities. You can call it a capacity market, but it will never be a real or natural market. With a natural market I mean a market where an actual need for goods or services is economically arranged. As far as power is concerned, this natural market is the euro per MWh market. Just like that other artificial market, the carbon market, the capacity market will only exist because the government has decided that it should exist. If the government decides to cancel the capacity market, it will cease to exist, and we will still be having power. If the natural euro per MWh market for power ceases to exist tomorrow, then our lights will go out.
Now why have politicians been convinced of the need to create this artificial market for capacity? Even if there is no natural need for it, does it cater for some deeper need that markets cannot detect? The argument in favor of capacity payments which is used by utilities and politicians is that the market in euro per MWh isn’t giving enough incentives to invest in power plant capacity in a way that safeguards long term security of supply.
Utilities naturally exaggerate this risk, using the powerful political argument of ‘the lights shutting down’. I don’t agree with that point of view, first of all because of personal experience. I have worked in the energy sector for 15 years and during that whole period I have heard about these threats of running out of power production capacity. The lights are still burning … Germany now produces large amounts of renewable energy. Industry insiders have always said that the intermittency issues of renewables would cause problems. Well, Germany has an extremely low outage rate of 15 minutes per power consumer per year, one of the lowest figures in the world.
Power supply systems have proven to be much more flexible and capable of adapting to changing circumstances than most analysts estimate. Utilities, analysts and politicians acknowledge that there is no problem at this moment. It would be very strange if they did so, considering that the low commodity prices for electricity at this moment have a solid basis in excess supply capacities. So, what the capacity payments are supposed to solve is a problem of the future. I was hesitating to write ‘potential problem’ here. But apparently, the proponents of capacity markets are not. They make powerful projections about a future in which a power supply shortage is certain to occur. That’s forecasting, and I’m always very skeptical of that, especially when it’s done by someone who has a conflict of interest, which is clearly the case for an industry representative lobbying to get an extra source of income. In particular, I think that in this case the forecasts of looming shortages are colored by a combination of neglect and exaggeration of the following aspects:
- The overall decline in power demand is often disregarded or minimized. Industry representatives link it too exclusively to the economic crisis. They assume (or hope?) that demand for power will start growing again as soon as the economic crisis is over. In doing so, they neglect more fundamental drivers of power demand decline such as delocalization of industry and most importantly the effects of climate policy. Just have a look at the reductions in capacity (Watts) of the lamps that you buy, and you will understand that consumption might nog just start growing again in a phase of economic expansion.
- Analysis of the long term capacity issues is too often limited to one country, neglecting the fact that cross-border trading can deliver a very important contribution to their solution. Shutting down gas-fired power stations in Germany might seem like a very big problem, but it is less so if you take into account the excess gas-fired power production capacities across the border in the Netherlands. EU Commissioner Oettinger is also against capacity payments and emphasizes the cross-border aspect. See for example the following article in the Frankfurter Algemeine. As far as the UK is concerned, for example, it is very curious that not more attention is paid to the idea of expanding the transmission lines across the Channel to continental Europe with its excess capacities and low prices.
- Many of the assumptions put forward by the proponents of capacity payments are simply not materializing. With more renewable energy on the grid, peakload – baseload spread would widen and spot markets would become excessively volatile. I really don’t see any proof of that. The system seems to be capable of absorbing much more variability than those who have designed and built in could have ever imagined. Still, many analysts continue to put these assumptions forward as a given and are followed in that by politicians, without anyone doing an attempt at providing empirical evidence.
- When utilities announce that they will shut down gas-fired power plants, they don’t always mean that these plants are taken offline definitively. There will be just a few cases in which the plants are actually completely shut down, with all the equipment dismantled. In many other cases, the utility will have the possibility of more or less rapidly re-opening the plant when prices (in euro’s per MWh) increase. Now, if we are really heading for a shortage of production, this increase is exactly what should happen. So, we might end up with a shortage of warm kW’s, power stations that are ready to start producing at any moment. That could cause prices to go up at certain moments. That would create an incentive for the utilities to warm up these kW’s again, something which might happen quite rapidly.
- Analysis of the market factors driving this situation is based on a static view of markets. In the last three years, the coal, natural gas, carbon price combination has been highly unfavorable for gas-fired power stations. It’s logical that utilities consider shutting down these ‘out-of-the-money’ plants. But when the gas-prices fall, these plants might get ‘in-the-money’ again quite rapidly. As a matter of fact, at this moment gas prices have dropped considerably. The spot price for gas has dropped below 16 euro’s per MWh recently, meaning that high-efficiency gas-fired power stations are turning in money when the electricity prices are in the lower thirties. Owners of gas-fired power stations should have been making reasonable amounts of money recently. Are they telling this to the politicians when they are lobbying for capacity payments?
What will capacity payments mean for end consumers?
Very simple: the price of electricity will go up. The capacity payments will be compensated by adding an extra cost item to end consumers’ electricity bills. Some argue that this will be compensated by lower commodity (euro per MWh) prices. I don’t think so. If the capacity payments are handed out to existing power stations, nothing changes to the merit order curve. The power stations will still switch on and off at the same marginal prices as before, so nothing will change to the market price. The only thing that will happen is that utilities will benefit from a source of income that they didn’t have before. The capacity payments will simply be a transfer of cash from power consumers to power producers. Can such a transfer be justified at this moment in our economy? Yes, utilities are turning in less cash than before. But should their customers be victimized for that?
For an end consumer, the conclusion is very simple. Mobilize your lobbying organization to avoid the introduction of capacity payments.
I can understand that for utilities the current situation isn’t nice. But they are not the first sector that goes through a phase of reduced profitability due to over-investment. That is the root cause of currently low prices. Utilities have over-invested in coal and gas-fired power capacity based on forecasts of a supply shortage that didn’t materialize. They have also invested a lot of money in renewable energy, raking in the subsidies that governments were giving for that. The marginal cost pricing made them win massive windfall profits on left of the curve assets in the 2005 – 2008 period when higher coal and gas prices caused marginal costs to go up to levels three times as high as what we currently see. Should the government step in immediately now that the wheel has spun around to the other side? Should they make the end consumer pay for that? Or should we rather say to the utility sector that it should accept normal entrepreneurial risk and don’t ask for a subsidy when their forecasts don’t materialize? Seeing assets turning in less money than expected is daily reality for businessmen in many different sectors. Why should the energy sector be an exception and get support from the government as soon as the weather turns bad on their investments? I see clients of mine in the food industry building large factories that in the best case will turn in just a few percentages of margin and assuming large risks in the soft commodity markets. They don’t ask for subsidies when they have a bad year.
For an end consumer, the conclusion is very simple. Mobilize your lobbying organization to avoid the introduction of capacity payments. At the same time, prepare yourself for its introduction by investigating possibilities for reducing its impact with load management.
What are the alternatives?
From the above, it might be clear that as a policy option, the introduction of capacity payments should be carefully considered. Especially since I believe that there are alternatives:
- The first one is very simple: just let the market work. If there is a shortage of (gas-fired) power production capacity, prices in those hours when gas-fired power stations are needed will rise high, creating an incentive for investment in gas-fired power capacity. Yes, the different speed of changes in demand and changes in supply will create bust and boom cycles in the prices. But that’s not unlike many other businesses.
- I totally agree with Mr. Oettinger that capacity issues need to be addressed on a European and not on a country-by-country scale. Enlarging the overall electrical system for which the supply and demand need to be balanced can seriously reduce the overall shortage. Consumption peaks will not occur at the same time in the different countries. And enlarging the ‘copper plate’ will also lead to more diversity in sources of supply, leading to a more balanced merit order curve and hence less problems with the marginal cost economics. If anything, the current issues should be a strong incentive to invest in extensions of cross-border connections. Belgium in particular should work on this instead of a capacity payment mechanism.
- When a shortage of gas-fired power station occurs, prices during the hours of peak consumption will rise, creating an incentive for consumers to reduce consumption during these hours. Again, let the market work. Addressing a supply-demand problem by working on the demand side will always be less expensive than working on the supply side. If the government wants to do anything, it could give further support to demand side management by creating incentives for large consumers to switch off capacity at peak moments through the regulated grid fees.
- As the example of the UK shows, the biggest issues occur when a production park becomes unbalanced. Well-diversified merit orders are the best guarantee for a healthy supply – demand balance. If the government wants to intervene, it could use its classical legislative instruments such as permit regulations to safeguard the diversity of the production park. Nowadays, permit procedures often take years, meaning that valuable time is lost in the adaptation of the supply side to changes in the market dynamics. Governments should do all they can to avoid this loss of time. In the case of Belgium, for example, I am convinced that the horribly slow permit procedures and the flip-flopping in the overall energy police have made a larger contribution to the current problem of looming capacity shortages than market deficiencies.
- If after all these previous measures there is still a shortage of power capacity, ‘reserve capacity’ support should be in the shape of support to grid companies for keeping gas-fired power stations open for absolute peak hours.
Here’s my plan for an alternative to the introduction of capacity payments, a more cost-efficient and fairer way of reducing capacity shortage, avoiding unnecessary increases of energy prices for the consumers:
- Continue the climate policy measures aimed at reducing consumption.
- Expand cross-border capacities and stimulate cross-border trading initiatives such as market coupling.
- Continue to support renewable energy, especially now that its investment costs have dropped. Combined with the previous measure more capacity on the left side of the merit order curve can reduce the need for more capacity on the right side.
- Support demand side management where it is realistic.
The end result could be a market where we produce ever lower amounts of power in renewable power stations and in gas-fired power stations at peak moments. If the grid in which this electricity is balanced is large enough and there is a good cushion of demand side adaptations, I don’t think that this will result in the sort of price peaks and blackouts that energy industry representatives predict. Introduction of capacity payments should be the solution of last resort, not the first thing we should think about. I know that if we introduce them only when the supply shortages manifest themselves, it will take some time for the extra capacity to be built. But I would rather risk two or three years of high peak prices and short blackout periods than risk an unnecessary and massive shift of money from power consumers to producers for solving a problem that in the end never materialized. We shouldn’t lightly risk creating a massive subsidy scheme that could result in over-capacity of unneeded gas-fired power stations.
Editor’s Note
Benedict de Meulemeester is owner/founder of the international energy and environment consultancy E&C (@EC_Consultants).This article was reproduced with permission from his blog http://energytics.wordpress.com.
Much to like, little to dislike. This comment is interesting:
“………..look at the reductions in capacity (Watts) of the lamps that you buy, and you will understand that consumption might not just start growing again in a phase of economic expansion”
The UK TSO National Grid noted that the evening peak has declined markedly – due to the adoption of low energy light bulbs. What is interesting is that the adoption of these is still at a relatively low level = much more demand reduction likely due to energy efficiency measures.
However, set against that, if the electrification of heating gathers pace one would expect some markets (such as the UK) to see a rise in demand. However, in the case of France (where electric heating is widespread) – one would expect to see a fall in demand – because French houses are thermally inefficient – & planned (?) energy efficiency measures would lead to quite a lot of French nuclear power – looking for somewhere to go (who knows – perhaps the French will also go for capacity markets?).
@Benedict, impressive nonsense. Of course consumers and industries urgently need a capacity payment system. Governments hold the monopoly in our energy markets. They determine (tax) on energy pricing. A capacity payment system is urgently needed in order to guarantee energy supplies and to keep the prices as low as possible. Without a capacity payment system new investments in power plants will come to a standstill. Germany will follow the UK very soon.
Arguments please?
Extra costs for similar security of supply… we have the same story with the French gas market and the “new” storage obligation.
“With a natural market I mean a market where an actual need for goods or services is economically arranged”
So there has been (since 2008) and will be quit some time no natural market for additional MWh’s in Germany. Even if these MWh’s are renewable. It is very true that falling demand is the main phenomenon but under these circumstances Germany’s continuing industrial policy (=subsidy) exaggerates the impact of that phenomenon.
The impact eventually will be loss of “flexibilty”. You propose to support (= subsidize) other “flexibilty options”. Maybe, for the time being, it is overall better to keep some of the existing options.
In the UK we have privatised the electricity industry but the Government’s Department of Energy & Climate Change (DECC) runs the market for renewables and back-up as though it was still in the public sector. There was better competition when it was all under the old State Central Electricity Generating Board.
The UK National Audit Office published a report today on the non-competitive manner under which the renewable electricity market in UK has been promoted by the DECC – see http://www.nao.org.uk/report/early-contracts-for-renewable-electricity/
Tim Yeo MP Chairman of the House of Commons ECC Committee spoke on radio today and tried to explain it away on grounds of security of supply etc.,!
i found the article very interesting.
the only point i’d like to make about electricty market and merit order effect, is that renewables are not competing on the same ground with conventional generation. renewable energy is more expensive than conventional and on a pure “natural market” intermittent renewables would be to the right of the merit order curve.
in reality, gas fired power plants have been shifted to the right of the merit order, because displaced from “must run” subsidized (feed in tariffs) renewable generation and reduction in the total grid load.
Most of the gas fired plants in Europe have been built before the introduction of feed in tariffs; these plants have become stranded assets due to government change in law, not due to natural market changes.
I’m not in favor of capacity payments, but i see a bit of logic about Utilities complaining to their Governments for making their investment not profitable by subsidizing intermittent renevables…
@Benedict: interesting article with a nice plan for alternatives. I very much agree to these alternatives, and would want to add the improved functioning of balancing markets and cross-border connection of balancing markets. In some markets we still would not be sure whether these alternatives would be picked up at sufficiently fast speed. Some of these alternatives (I call them flexibility measures) at the moment are not cost-effective, so some support would be needed to bring them to the market. Critics would say that this means subsidising such alternatives, which is true. So why then subsidise these flexibility measures and not the supply side flexibility measure of keeping fossil fuel capacity in the market? This question can be answered from various angles: some options are preferred over others, from societal point of view, environmental point of view, or perhaps from the point of view of preserving jobs. That choice is to be made by society, with policy makers as their representatives. Fact is that if a choice is made to support one option only (such as supporting fossil fuelled capacity via a capacity market) then this creates a competitive advantage over other flexibility options, which could hamper their market penetration. Furthermore, supporting fossil fuelled capacity may create lock-in effects and therewith hamper the further growth of renewables.
A key issue in this is that the current energy only markets were not designed with the large shares of renewables in mind that are currently included in the system and that we need to take some short-term measures to further support system balancing while not limiting their further growth. To ‘solve’ this matter let’s first improve the energy-only markets, with among others improved balancing markets and international linking of such markets. Then IF it would be concluded that additional flexibility is needed then let’s at least ensure that it is not biased towards only supporting one option, but let’s also support other options. In other words, then establish a flexibility market in which all flexibility options can provide their benefits and obtain additional support, not just one selected option.
For more reading: we published an article along these lines a few weeks ago (tinyurl.com/qabsf7h, in Dutch). More to come as result of a study we are currently conducting for the European Commission (to be published later).
@MonigueVoogt. Super response, clearly demonstrating you have seriously plumbed the depths of this issue. I’m only sorry I don’t read Dutch! To add my two cents, the author of the blog tends to confuse capacity markets and capacity payments. While I see no need for either, a competitive capacity MARKET, open to all players, particularly commercial demand side managers, is not the same as government subsidies in the form of capacity PAYMENTS to particular types of generation. In some areas of the US with advanced electricity market structures, commercial aggregators of demand side response are making a good living. These demand side management traders pay electricity users up front for committing to reduce their electricity consumption on demand and then sell this negative demand into the market when prices rise due to a shortage of supply. They make their profit on the difference between buy and sell prices. Instant, effective, simple, rational and positive for the environment. Should the worst happen in Europe and the system not be flexible enough to continue today’s high levels of supply security, a strategic reserve, to be called on if and when needed, is a far cheaper and simpler solution than a capacity market monster or capacity payments. Even such a reserve should only be a temporary solution until electricity markets are restructured to the needs of a renewables dominated system. Meantime, the development of proper competitive markets for ancillary services (grid support services) could well make a mirage of any perceived need for capacity payments. Think about it.
@Paolo
You should not think profitable is the same as cheap. We now see that renewables were the cheapest option compared to natural gas, the main point is that large utilities were thinking natural gas were more profitable as they are able to increase the market price of electricity. It’s their own greed that killed them.
There is quite a good explaination about how marginal cost based price leads to massive building of natural gas power plants to manipulate the maket by raising the electricity price and make more profit.
http://www.eurotrib.com/story/2011/3/27/112744/639
So naturally in a marginal cost based power market, greedy players will build a massive amount of natural gas power plant. However they take also a high risk because if one of their competitor build renewable power their gas power plant will not be used at all, same thing if there is a decrease in consumption due to energy efficiency : both happened. They also knew that it would happen because there was already laws and directives aiming at improving energy efficiency and adding renewables long before they made their investment and they knew they had new competitors looking to build renewable power plant. Less consumption and more renewables : how could they not get that it would lead to less fossil fuel ? That was a very risky bet.
In a market based economy, profits are not guaranteed by the states… plain and simple. You take a huge risk to get a huge reward (they got a lot of money in the 2000’s BTW), the downside is you will get a huge punishment if that does not work.
So now should we reward speculation by bailing out greedy players aiming at the short term or should we let the market reward people who had the long term in mind ?
The prime goal of an electricity system is to provide reliable electricity for the user. Anything short of complete reliability is unacceptable. Even more, for the European economy to remain competitive the electricity system must not only be reliable, but it must also be perceived as being reliable. In the present state of affairs, intermittent renewables cannot provide that level of reliability and perceived reliability. Hence the need to buy “reliability insurance” in the form of capacity payments.
@Lyn, I think you make some excellent points, except that you do the author an injustice by saying he does not distinguish between capacity payments and capacity mechanisms. He clearly does. I may have contributed to this confusion, though, by adding an introduction in which I used the word capacity mechanism where I should have used capacity payments.I will amend that now.
The point you make about keeping a strategic reserve had also occurred to me. Grid operators could do this quite simply. In fact, I think they do so already!
-Karel Beckman, editor Energy Post
So informative stuff here!! Absolutely true that “Grid utilization remained a monopolistic market and continued to receive money based on a regulated tariff with the dual kW and MWh structure. That’s quite logical. Grid companies have high Capex and fixed costs, due to the high investments that are necessary for building the grids”.