
Solar farm in North Carolina
The world is undergoing a dramatic electricity transition, and the global struggle for power over this transformed electric system is set to profoundly shape our future, argues Walt Patterson, Associate Fellow in the Energy, Environment and Resource Department of Chatham House in London. According to Patterson, politics, not economics, will determine the outcome of this struggle. Article courtesy Hoffmann Centre for Sustainable Resource Economy.
Whose power ?
Electricity means power. That, at least, has long been a common English usage â think of power stations, power lines, power companies, power systems. People use the word âpowerâ as a direct synonym for electricity but it is far more than electricity. Power is one of the most important concepts in human society.
On a personal level, power is the ability to do what you want to do. On a social level, power is the ability to make others do what you want them to do. How did electricity become power? How does electric power interact with other aspects of power? As the world’s electricity undergoes a dramatic, hectic transition, what might the transition imply for power in global society?
Disputes about electricity policy, planning, investment and the associated costs â and who pays them â have always been couched in economic terms: which option is cheapest, offers the best value for money and so on. But such disputes are first and foremost political â a struggle for power between different participants in electricity systems. Even the putative economic evaluation depends on who is evaluating and how.
One striking difference, arising from the altered technical configurations of innovative electricity, is that Samuel Insullâs ânatural monopolyâ argument that a locality could economically justify only one set of wires, no longer applies
Throughout the first century of public electricity provision, until the 1990s, in the many confrontations that occurred around the world, the power almost invariably lay with centralized agents â governments or franchised monopoly companies or often both â rather than with individual citizens and electricity users. The siting of a transmission line, dam or power station, the choice of generating technology, the control of emissions, the disposal of waste and safety concerns were all decided by these centralized agents regardless of public opposition. So was the cost users paid for electricity from the public system. Captive customers of monopoly power had no choice.
The situation was akin to the status of telecommunications. Throughout the world, telephone systems, whether state-owned or private, were franchised monopolies that laid down stringent restrictions on their customers. Later governments began to break up these franchised monopolies and to liberalize telecommunications.
The Hoffmann Centre for Sustainable Resource Economy is a new endeavour founded at Chatham House last year. The Hoffmann Centreâs mission is âto accelerate the uptake of smart policies, technologies and business models that will reshape the worldâs demand for resources and transform the global economy.”Â
Then along came the internet, wireless mobiles, tablets and smartphones, which within two decades caused a spectacular transformation. Customers who had been effectively powerless under the traditional regime found that they could now choose providers and types of connectivity, communicate by text, voice or video over any distance, access information and entertainment at will, and collaborate with others anywhere â powers previously in the realm of science-fiction.
A similarly rapid, comprehensive and disruptive transformation is now happening to electricity. Driving it is a combination of technological innovation and institutional upheaval. The technological innovation is affecting not only generation but also networks and end-use equipment and the software linking them â a striking reorganization of system configurations, the facilities involved and where and how they function.
The corollary is an equally striking shake-up of regulatory and business relations. The overall effect is a gradual but unambiguous diminution of the power of the traditional centralized players, the rise of new centralized players and a gradual but accelerating increase in the power of those previously at the edges of the centralized system.
Breaking the mould
The traditional centralized model assumed huge remote generators feeding long high-voltage transmission lines carrying large currents in one direction via local distribution networks to passive loads on the premises of users.
The rise of reliable smaller-scale generation broke the mould: gas turbines in combined cycles; gas engines offering cogeneration or even trigeneration, electricity, heat and cooling; then wind power; then photovoltaics, among others. The rise of wind and solar power â both fire-free forms of generation â reduces system dependence on fuel, with its variable and unpredictable future costs and its inevitable environmental impact.
Innovative generation has been accompanied by innovative network facilities and corresponding software â including Flexible Alternating Current Transmission System (FACTS) and high-voltage direct current (HVDC). These network technologies still fit into the traditional decision-making power structure, with investment and management by large centralized players. But they also foster more flexible and versatile system configuration and operation, loosening system boundaries and making existing assets more amenable to reorganization.
The inevitable corollary of decentralized electricity must be a fundamental rethink of the very idea of regulation and with all that that implies for political and economic power
As this technical evolution continues, in more and more places the traditional system is gradually turning into a more decentralized configuration, with smaller units of generation, many of these closer to users with users themselves becoming generators. A yet more disruptive technical innovation is also coming into play â affordable battery storage at scales from household to substation.
The abundant technical options now available offer the opportunity to set up complete and coherent, integrated and optimized local systems, including generation, networks and high-performance loads, all communicating with one another in so-called ‘microgrids’. Such a microgrid may be connected to a traditional system.
It may, however, be free-standing and able to operate independently, either in emergency âislandâ mode or as a normal complete system. As more microgrids emerge, they may in turn be interconnected for load-levelling and backup â effectively a âfederationâ of microgrids with operating, management and financial arrangements far removed from the traditional centralized power structure.
Microgrids in rural settings, controlled by and serving local people, are already emerging in Southeast Asia, and they present major opportunities for other parts of the world beyond the reach of traditional networks. Can these regions, including more than a billion people still without electric light, establish decentralized village microgrids to leapfrog traditional centralized electricity and its institutional power structure? The potential is enormous, and obvious, but the centralized players are still mostly stubbornly opposed to such loss of political power, despite their inability to deliver.
Towards decentralization
Gradual decentralization of the technical model of electricity systems brings with it a parallel decentralization of decision-making power, disrupting the institutional arrangements of traditional electricity.
New players, such as universities, airports, hospitals, shopping malls, office blocks, communities, villages â and even single individuals â acquire the power to invest in and to connect and control electricity facilities. Not just user technology but generators, networks, software and entire systems. They also acquire the power to select and to change business partners as well as the types of business activities and relationships, and, not least, to refuse an offer.
These new decentralized powers gravely threaten the business model of the traditional centralized players. They also offer an appetizing menu of potential opportunities for new business activities and relationships for the traditional players and the new arrivals. In the Netherlands, for example, the green energy company Vandebron links many small-scale solar, wind and biomass generators with users of electricity. The generators decide what they want to charge and the users decide whose electricity they want to buy. This peer-to-peer relationship is still novel for electricity but could become much more common.
Power will determine where, how and how much money is invested. Power will determine how revenue flows and to whom
Decentralized and differentiated technical configurations will also entail profound changes in the prevailing institutional framework for electricity, which may not be welcomed by those who as yet still exercise most of the relevant economic and political power.
One striking difference, arising from the altered technical configurations of innovative electricity, is that Samuel Insullâs ânatural monopolyâ argument that a locality could economically justify only one set of wires, no longer applies. The ânatural monopolyâ argument gave rise to the âregulated monopoly franchiseâ concept. The inevitable corollary of decentralized electricity must be a fundamental rethink of the very idea of regulation and with all that that implies for political and economic power.
The traditional unilateral electricity transaction essentially offered users a âHobsonâs choiceâ: take it or leave it. The new entrepreneurial context will be a dramatic break with that unequal tradition. Users will have the power to negotiate and interrogate prospective providers and to also select the best option.
That in turn may entail different business relationships based, not on short-term commodity transactions, but on longer-term contracts between providers and clients, and not on selling kilowatt-hours but on providing the services people want. Instead of the lopsided power wielded by the suppliers of traditional electricity, in these new relationships, the balance of power ought to be more or less equal, with contract terms offering mutual benefits to both parties.
Although the electric transformation is taking place mainly for sound business reasons, its emphasis on higher-performance gas-fired generation, especially cogeneration and trigeneration, plus entirely fire-free wind and solar generation, may gradually but unambiguously reduce the hitherto vast and dominant economic and political power of traditional fuel suppliers.
Gas-fired and fire-free electricity undercuts the power of the coal industry; electric vehicles undercut the power of the oil industry; better buildings in whole-system upgrades undercut the power of the natural gas industry. What is emerging is a contest of electricity versus fire. Some power is gradually being decentralized, but large-scale wind and solar fire-free generation is also becoming ever more significant.
The struggle under way is thus intensely political. Politics, not economics, will determine the course of electricityâs evolution. Power will determine where, how and how much money is invested. Power will determine how revenue flows and to whom. Some new players, large and small, will be winners. Some traditional players, previously large and unchallenged, may be losers. But they will not go quietly.
Editorâs Note
Walt Patterson is Associate Fellow, Energy, Environment and Resources at The Hoffmann Center for Sustainable Resource Economy, base at Chatham House in London. He has published 14 books and hundreds of papers on a wide variety of energy topics. His latest book, Electricity vs Fire: The Fight for our Future, is available as a free download on his website, Â waltpatterson.org
This article was first published on the website of the Hoffmann Centre for Sustainable Resource Economy and is republished here with permission.
[adrotate banner=”78″]
Great piece. The only small gripe is with the characterization of what exactly no longer fits Samuel Insull’s natural monopoly vision – it is still the case, and will probably be for some time, that “one set of wires” will be the most economic solution and the one to which the system reverts post-disruption (whatever form that takes), but otherwise agree with Patterson that nothing else in the value chain fits Insull’s treasured natural monopoly model anymore. Where I agree with Patterson when it comes to wires, what’s most economic in the way of wires at the most local level may not necessarily be the short-term choice of local communities, of course, and one could envision local communities abandoning the local DSO to set up their own micro-grid (which would not be cheap, so we’re probably talking about powerful wealthy communities and industrial/commercial clusters) and successfully demanding that the transmission operators connect them to the high-voltage backbone, leaving the DSOs owning stranded assets. But for the overall system the more likely route, perhaps spurred by such maverick communities, is for DSOs to become platforms connected to the high-voltage backbone, facilitating multi-directional power flows below that level for all comers (just as the breakdown of the telecoms monopolies and of the other parts of the electricity value chain were spurred by maverick end-users bypassing the incumbent monopoly, ultimately paving the way for wider choices for all end-users, such as when the industrial CHP I developed in upstate New York in the late 1980s became the first end-use consumer to successfully bypass usurious Niagara Mohawk gas interconnection fees to connect directly to the interstate pipeline two miles away). And as Patterson points out, the “powers” that be will not go quietly (NiMo certainly didn’t) – it is conceivable that DSOs as a category will simply disappear, their current functions either being absorbed by the more technologically sophisticated and scale-advantaged TSOs or devolved to local communities, as appropriate. But those platforms would, for the foreseeable future, still be “one set of wires” – it will not be economically sustainable for dueling sets of wires trying to bring electricity the “last mile.”
This article reads as a paean to the ideology of decentralization. I’m all in favor of decentralization — when it makes sense — but elevating it to the status of ideology is stupid. It demonizes centralized solutions, even in cases where a centralized approach is more efficient and more reliable.
Distribution of electric power over power lines has been and always will be a natural monopoly. Yes, new technology has made it easier to accommodate distributed generation, and that’s great. Microgrids that can be islanded from the main grid make sense for preserving power if the main grid is taken out. Robust is good. But the hoops and extra regulatory nonsense that utilities have been burdened with in ideologically-driven efforts to “de-regulate” a natural monopoly have (in my opinion) done far more harm than good.